10. American Options#

In the following \(\Cam\) or \(\Pam\) denote an American call or put respectively, whereas their European counterparts are denoted by \(C\) or \(P.\)

10.1. American Options Characteristics#

10.1.1. American vs. European Option Premium#

The main difference of American options compared to their European counterparts is that they can be exercised early. Knowing when to optimally exercise an American call or put is a challenging problem. This is the main reason why it is harder to price American options.

Because an American option has all the benefits of a European option but in addition has the possibility of early exercise, it has to be the case that its premium is at least as high as the premium on a European option with the same characteristics, i.e. we must have that \(\Cam \geq C\) and \(\Pam \geq P\).

10.1.2. Early-Exercise of American Options#

It is never optimal to exercise early an American call option when the asset pays no dividends as long as the risk-free rate is positive. To see why, notice that if \(r > 0\), then we have that:

\[\begin{equation*} \Cam \geq C \geq S - K e^{-r T} > S - K. \end{equation*}\]

If it were optimal to exercise early, the price of the American call would be equal to its intrinsic value, violating the strict inequality. Intuitively, if interest rates are positive, there is no opportunity cost for not holding the stock but there is a benefit for holding cash. Hence, you are better off waiting until maturity to get the stock.

This implies that for non-dividend paying stocks the value of an American call option with maturity \(T\) and strike price \(K\) is the same to the value of a European call option with the same characteristics.

When there are dividends, it might be optimal to exercise early an American call option just before the stock goes ex-dividend. For American puts the situation is similar, even when on assets with no-dividends.

In summary, exercising early is all about opportunity costs. If there is no opportunity cost in waiting, then it is never optimal to exercise early.

10.2. Put-Call Parity#

Property 10.1 (Put-Call Parity for American Options)

For American options written on non-dividend paying stocks, the put-call parity holds as two inequalities if \(r > 0\):

\[\begin{equation*} S - K \leq \Cam - \Pam \leq S - K e^{-r T} \end{equation*}\]

Interestingly, these inequalities are reversed if \(r < 0\):

\[\begin{equation*} S - K e^{-r T} \leq \Cam - \Pam \leq S - K \end{equation*}\]

Both inequalities imply that put-call parity holds in the same way as for European options if \(r = 0\):

\[\begin{equation*} \Cam - \Pam = S - K \end{equation*}\]

To see why \(\Cam - \Pam \leq S - K e^{-r T}\) when \(r > 0\), note that the American call is never exercised early when the asset pays no dividends and \(r > 0\), hence its value is equal to that of the European option, i.e. \(\Cam = C\). For the American put, on the other hand, it might be optimal to exercise early if the option is deep in-the-money, implying that \(\Pam \geq P\). Putting everything together:

\[\begin{equation*} \Pam \geq P = C - S + K e^{-r T} = \Cam - S + K e^{-r T} \end{equation*}\]

or

\[\begin{equation*} \Cam - \Pam \leq S - K e^{-r T} \end{equation*}\]

Now we turn our attention to see why \(S - K \leq \Cam - \Pam\) when \(r > 0\).

Strategy A: Long put and long stock

\[\begin{align*} \text{Cost} & = \Pam + S \\ \text{Payoff} & = \begin{cases} K - S_{\tau} + S_{\tau} = K & \text{if put is exercised at time $\tau \leq T$} \\ S_{T} & \text{if put is never exercised} \end{cases} \end{align*}\]

Strategy B: Long call and \(K\) today in a money-market account

\[\begin{align*} \text{Cost} & = \Cam + K \\ \text{Payoff} & = \begin{cases} \Cam_{\tau} + K e^{r \tau} \geq K & \text{if put is exercised at time $\tau \leq T$} \\ S_{T} - K + K e^{r T} \geq S_{T} & \text{if put is never exercised} \end{cases} \end{align*}\]

Since the payoffs of strategy B dominate those of strategy A, we can conclude that the cost of B is greater than the cost of A, or that \(\Cam + K \geq \Pam + S\) which is the same as \(S - K \leq \Cam - \Pam\).

What happens when \(r < 0\)? In this case the American put is never exercised early when the asset pays no dividends and \(r < 0\), hence its value is equal to that of the European option, i.e. \(\Pam = P\). For the American call, on the other hand, it might be optimal to exercise early if the option is deep in-the-money, implying that \(\Cam \geq C\). Thus:

\[\begin{equation*} \Cam \geq C = P + S - K e^{-r T} = \Pam - S + K e^{-r T} \end{equation*}\]

which shows that:

\[\begin{equation*} \Cam - \Pam \geq S - K e^{-r T} \end{equation*}\]

To see why \(\Cam - \Pam \leq S - K\) when \(r < 0\), let us analyze the following strategies.

Strategy A: Long put and long stock

\[\begin{align*} \text{Cost} & = \Pam + S \\ \text{Payoff} & = \begin{cases} S_{\tau} & \text{if call is exercised at time $\tau \leq T$} \\ K - S_{T} + S_{T} = K & \text{if call is never exercised} \end{cases} \end{align*}\]

Strategy B: Long call and \(K\) today in a money-market account

\[\begin{align*} \text{Cost} & = \Cam + K \\ \text{Payoff} & = \begin{cases} S_{\tau} - K + K e^{r \tau} \leq S_{\tau} & \text{if call is exercised at time $\tau \leq T$} \\ K e^{r T} \leq K & \text{if call is never exercised} \end{cases} \end{align*}\]

Since the payoffs of strategy A dominate those of strategy B, we can conclude that the cost of A is greater than the cost of B, or that \(\Cam + K \leq \Pam + S\) which is the same as \(\Cam - \Pam \leq S - K\).

Example 10.1

On 2/8/17, Facebook (FB) closing price was $134.20. As of that date, the stock does not pay dividends. Options on FB as on other stocks are American. Let us consider options on FB with maturity date 6/17/17. This implies that \(T = 129 / 365 = 0.35\). If we use a continuously compounded interest rate of 1.5% per year, we can compute the no-arbitrage bounds on these options.

Strike

Call Price

Put Price

\(S - K\)

\(\Cam - \Pam\)

\(S - K e^{-r T}\)

120

17.30

2.50

14.20

14.80

14.83

125

13.61

3.75

9.20

9.86

9.86

130

10.25

5.45

4.20

4.80

4.89

135

7.45

7.60

-0.80

-0.15

-0.09

140

5.13

10.35

-5.80

-5.22

-5.06

145

3.47

13.65

-10.80

-10.18

-10.03

As can be seen from the table, the difference between calls and puts is well within the bounds predicted by the theory for all strikes.

10.3. Option Bounds#

As with European options, the premium of an American type option must be bounded above and below to prevent arbitrage opportunities.

If it is not optimal to exercise early, then an American call option is just a European call option and the pricing bounds that we saw before apply. For example, it is never optimal to early-exercise an American call written on a non-dividend paying asset if \(r > 0.\) In that case we must have:

\[\begin{equation*} \max(S - K e^{-r T}, 0) \leq \Cam = C \leq S \end{equation*}\]

If we are analyzing a case where it might be optimal to exercise the American call option early, such as when the stock pays a dividend yield \(q > 0,\) we then have the following pricing bounds.

First, the American call premium cannot be less than its intrinsic value. Indeed, we must have that \(\Cam \geq 0.\) Additionally, when the American call is in-the-money, if its premium was less than its intrinsic value, it would make sense to purchase the American call and exercise immediately which would yield an instantaneous arbitrage profit. This implies that the time value of the American call cannot be negative.

Second, the American call cannot trade for more than the price of its underlying asset. If not, it would make sense for an arbitrageur to sell the American call and buy the stock, generating an instantaneous profit. If the call is exercised at any point before or at maturity, the payoff of this strategy would be the strike price of the call. If not, the call will expire out-of-the-money and the arbitrageur could then sell the stock. This strategy is clearly an arbitrage since it generates a positive cash flow today and in the future.

Therefore, the principle of no-arbitrage implies that

\[\begin{equation*} \max(S - K, 0) \leq \Cam \leq S. \end{equation*}\]

For American put options we have a similar result. On the one hand, to prevent arbitrage opportunities, the put premium cannot be negative and when the American put is in-the-money, the time-value of the American put cannot be negative as well.

On the other hand, the American put cannot trade for more than the strike. It not, it would make sense for an arbitrageur to sell the put and invest an amount equal to the strike in a risk-free account. This strategy generates a positive cash flow today and if the put is exercised, the money market account will have more than enough funds to buy the stock for \(K\) from the buyer of the put, at which point it can be sold at its current price.

Thus,

\[\begin{equation*} \max(K - S, 0) \leq \Pam \leq K. \end{equation*}\]

10.4. Factors Affecting American Option Prices#

Variable

America Call

American Put

Current stock price

\(+\)

\(-\)

Strike price

\(-\)

\(+\)

Time-to-expiration

\(+\)

\(+\)

Volatility

\(+\)

\(+\)

Risk-free rate

\(+\)

\(-\)

10.5. Binomial Pricing of American Options#

In order to accommodate the binomial pricing framework to American options, we need to allow for the possibility of early exercise at any point in time. This means that we should always compare the intrinsic value of the option, i.e. the value of exercising now, with the value of continuing given by the discounted risk-neutral expected value of future payoffs.

We will start by pricing an American put option on a non-dividend paying asset. To make the valuation problem interesting, we will use a two-period binomial tree.

As with European options, the spot rate is given by \(S\) and each period the spot rate goes up by \(u\) or goes down by \(d\) with risk-neutral probabilities \(p\) and \(1 - p\), respectively. Therefore:

  • \(S_{u} = S \times u\) and \(S_{d} = S \times d\)

  • \(S_{uu} = S_{u} \times u\), \(S_{ud} = S_{u} \times d = S_{d} \times u = S_{du}\) and \(S_{dd} = S_{d} \times d\)

An American put option expiring at \(T\) and strike \(K\) trades at \(\Pam\). The time-step is then \(\Delta T = T / 2.\)

The figure below shows the two-period tree for the spot and the American put option.

Figure made with TikZ

We now turn our attention to price the American put. First, note that the value of the American put at expiration is just the intrinsic value of the option:

\[\begin{align*} \Pam_{uu} & = \max(K - S_{uu}, 0) \\ \Pam_{ud} & = \max(K - S_{ud}, 0) \\ \Pam_{dd} & = \max(K - S_{dd}, 0) \end{align*}\]

If the spot rate goes up:

  • The intrinsic value of the put is \(I_{u} = \max(K - S_{u}, 0)\).

  • The continuation value is \(H_{u} = (p \Pam_{uu} + (1 - p) \Pam_{ud}) e^{-r \Delta t}\).

  • If \(I_{u} > H_{u}\) then the option should be exercised immediately, otherwise we should wait.

  • Therefore, the price of the option at that time is \(\Pam_{u} = \max(H_{u}, I_{u})\).

Similarly, if the spot rate goes down, we have that \(\Pam_{d} = \max(H_{d}, I_{d})\).

Finally, the value of the American put is given by \(\Pam = \max(H, I)\), where:

\[\begin{align*} H & = \left( p \Pam_{u} + (1 - p) \Pam_{d} \right) e^{-r \Delta t} \\ I & = \max(K - S, 0) \end{align*}\]

Example 10.2

Let us price an American put option with maturity 6 months and strike $100 written on a non-dividend paying stock using a two-step binomial model. The current stock price is $100, and it can go up or down by 5% each period for two periods. Each period represents 3-months, i.e. \(\Delta t = 0.25\). The risk-free rate is 6% per year (continuously compounded).

Figure made with TikZ


The risk-neutral probability of an up-move is:

\[\begin{equation*} p = \frac{e^{r \Delta t} - d}{u - d} = \frac{e^{0.06 \times 0.25} - 0.95}{1.05 - 0.95} = 0.6511 \end{equation*}\]

The risk-neutral probability of a down-move is just \(1 - p = 0.3489\). We then have that:

\[\begin{align*} H_{u} & = \left( 0 \times p + 0.25 \times (1 - p) \right) e^{-0.06 \times 0.25} = 0.09 \\ I_{u} & = \max(100 - 105, 0) = 0 \end{align*}\]

so that \(\Pam_{u} = \max(0.08, 0) = 0.09\), and

\[\begin{align*} H_{d} & = \left( 0.25 \times p + 9.75 \times (1 - p) \right) e^{-0.06 \times 0.25} = 3.51 \\ I_{d} & = \max(100 - 95, 0) = 5 \end{align*}\]

which implies that \(\Pam_{d} = \max(3.51, 5) = 5\).

Finally,

\[\begin{align*} H & = \left( 0.09 \times p + 5 \times (1 - p) \right) e^{-0.06 \times 0.25} = 1.78 \\ I & = \max(100 - 100, 0) = 0 \end{align*}\]

so that \(\Pam = \max(1.78, 0) = \$1.78\).

Note that the value of a European put with the same characteristics is \(P = \$1.26\), implying that the early-exercise premium is \(1.78 - 1.26 = \$0.52\). Also, you can verify that the value of an American call with the same characteristics is the same as the value of a European call, which is $4.22.

10.6. Practice Problems#

Exercise 10.1

Explain why an American option is always worth at least as much as a European option on the same asset with the same strike price and exercise date.

Exercise 10.2

Explain why an American call option is always worth at least as much as its intrinsic value. Is the same true of a European call option? Explain your answer.

Exercise 10.3

Give an intuitive explanation of why the early exercise of an American put becomes more attractive as the risk-free rate increases and volatility decreases.

Exercise 10.4

The price of an American call on a non-dividend-paying stock is $4. The stock price is $31, the strike price is $30, and the expiration date is in three months. The risk-free interest rate is 8% per year with continuous compounding. Derive upper and lower bounds for the price of an American put on the same stock with the same strike price and expiration date.

Exercise 10.5

Suppose that \(S = 110\), \(r = 4\%\), \(q = 8\%\), and \(\sigma = 40\%\). Using a two-period binomial tree, compute the no-arbitrage price of an American call option with strike $112 and maturity 8 months.

Exercise 10.6

The current price of a non-dividend paying stock is $100. Every three months, it is expected to go up or down by 16% or 12%, respectively. The risk-free rate is 9% per year with continuous compounding. Compute the price of an American put option with strike price $98 and maturity six months written on the stock.

Exercise 10.7

The current price of a stock is $100. Every three months, it is expected to go up or down by 19% or 11%, respectively. The stock pays a dividend yield of 7% per year and the risk-free rate is 7% per year with continuous compounding. Compute the price of an American call option with strike price $98 and maturity six months written on the stock.

Exercise 10.8

Consider an American put option written over a non-dividend paying asset. Which of the following alternatives is correct?

  1. The option should never be exercised early.

  2. It might be optimal to exercise the option early if the interest rate is positive.

  3. The price of the American put should be the same as an American call with the same characteristics.

  4. It might be optimal to exercise the option early if the interest rate is negative.